It’s the 4th of July and a good day to think
about revolution.
The good news from last month’s job report is that job
growth continues, and compared with every Western nation save Canada, the US
seems like a beacon of job creation. The bad news is that job growth continues to
be anemic: in contrast to the 2nd terms of any recent president,
Obama’s second term average monthly job creation number of 202,000 is ranked last,
behind Clinton, Nixon, Reagan, and GW Bush. Admittedly, no president has had to
swim upstream against such steady layoffs from the government sector during a
recovery. But then again no president has had such a large labor pool; simply
adjusted for the size of the work force, Obama’s job creation numbers should
run about double Nixon’s.
It might be worth considering the possibility that something
is different about this economy. Taken as a whole, there has been no time since
the Great Depression that the West has done so poorly at job creation.
I think that an argument can be made that we need a new set
of policies to acknowledge the possibility that we’re in a new Entrepreneurial
Economy that is as different from the Information Economy into which we were
born as that was from the Industrial Economy before it. If my theory is right,
this new economy suggests that we will have to develop a new set of policies to
popularize entrepreneurship as much as we popularized knowledge work in the last
century. Before we can make sense of
this new economy and begin to formulate effective policies, we need to
understand a pattern of progress.
Since the Dark Ages, the West has had at least three
distinct market economies. The same pattern of change that created them is now
creating a fourth.
Economy
|
~ Period
|
1st Agricultural
|
1300 to 1700
|
2nd Industrial
|
1700 to 1900
|
3rd Information
|
1900 to 2000
|
4th Entrepreneurial
|
2000 to ~
|
These economies are defined by their limits to progress.
Progress in an Industrial Economy, for example, is limited by
capital – industrial and financial. As a community in an Industrial Economy
creates and attracts more capital, it becomes more rich and powerful.
But just
as what limits a baby’s development is different from what limits a teenager’s,
so it is with economies at different stages of development. At a certain point,
an industrial community has enough factories to make more than enough products
and now needs knowledge workers who can design better products, more efficient
processes, and stimulate demand. Manipulation of things gives way to the manipulation
of symbols, and an Industrial Economy limited by capital gives way to an
Information Economy limited by knowledge workers. Limits shift and as communities
adapt and attempt to overcome the new limit, they begin to create a new
economy. Eventually information does as much to distract as inform, and
university graduates struggle to find jobs that pay enough for them to pay back
student loans and the rent.
Economy
|
Period
|
Limit
to Progress
|
1st Agricultural
|
1300 to 1700
|
Land
|
2nd Industrial
|
1700 to 1900
|
Capital
|
3rd Information
|
1900 to 2000
|
Knowledge Workers
|
4th Entrepreneurial
|
2000 ~
|
Entrepreneurship
|
Economies depend on invention for progress. Nobody denies
that. Curiously, though, technological inventions like steam engines and computers
get more attention in discussions about progress than do social inventions like
banks and the modern corporation. Yet social inventions are just as important.
Business entrepreneurship – starting a business – is just
one form of social invention.
It might be easy to understand that a nation-state with a
standing army to defend (or even extend) borders is important to an economy
limited by land.
It might be harder to understand that as communities
struggle to overcome the limit of entrepreneurship they’ll have to popularize social
invention. This suggests a different idea of self. A self defined by the big
institutions is different from a self who defines them. It’s very different to
be a good Catholic or good British citizen than to be a Protestant or American
revolutionary. To be a good employee is very different than to be a good entrepreneur.
The popularization of entrepreneurship – or social invention – will rely on a
very different notion of the individual, a new kind of self.
Economy
|
Period
|
Limit
to Progress
|
New
Social Invention
|
1st Agricultural
|
1300 to 1700
|
Land
|
Nation-State
|
2nd Industrial
|
1700 to 1900
|
Capital
|
Bank
|
3rd Information
|
1900 to 2000
|
Knowledge Workers
|
Modern Corporation
|
4th Entrepreneurial
|
2000 ~
|
Entrepreneurship
|
Self
|
The pattern of progress doesn’t just result in new social
inventions: it transforms the old ones. The Medieval Church did not meekly
yield to the new nation-state. Monarchs in the 2nd economy didn’t
easily yield power to the new capitalists. But in spite of resistance, the institutions
created by and run for elites become a tool for the masses. Martin Luther proclaims
that “We are all priests,” or Thomas Jefferson writes, “All men are created
equal,” and the power of popes to define beliefs or of monarchs to define
policy becomes a power of the common person.
This pattern will repeat again in the fourth economy; rather than use
the individual as a tool, the corporation, just as the church, state, and bank
before it, will become a tool for the average person.
Economy
|
Period
|
Limit
to Progress
|
New
Social Invention
|
Social
Transformation
|
1st Agricultural
|
1300 to 1700
|
Land
|
Nation-State
|
Religion (Protestant Revolution)
|
2nd Industrial
|
1700 to 1900
|
Capital
|
Bank
|
Politics (Democratic Revolution)
|
3rd Information
|
1900 to 2000
|
Knowledge Workers
|
Modern Corporation
|
Finance
|
4th Entrepreneurial
|
2000 ~
|
Entrepreneurship
|
Self
|
Business
|
We don’t just invent and transform institutions. We invent
and transform ways of thinking.
Successful business entrepreneurs create a system that
generates more value than it costs. Like systems thinkers, they focus on the interaction
of parts as much as the action of the parts, working towards value that emerges
out of these interactions. A knowledge worker focuses on a specialty; the
entrepreneur looks at the whole. Knowledge work is enhanced by pragmatism and
entrepreneurship is enhanced by systems thinking.
Of course our modern world is defined by systems – manmade
information and transportation systems that rest atop – and interact with - climate
and ecosystems. One way to frame the central challenge of our time is to create
sustainable and stable systems – from financial systems to industrial systems.
And incidentally, becoming more adept at understanding, creating, modifying,
and harmonizing with systems will make us more adept at entrepreneurship, at
social invention. As we begin to organize our world around the principles of
systems thinking we’re likely to change our world as much as the Enlightenment
thinkers of the American colonies changed theirs.
Economy
|
Period
|
Limit
to Progress
|
New
Social Invention
|
Social
Transformation
|
New
Way of Thinking
|
1st Agricultural
|
1300 to 1700
|
Land
|
Nation-State
|
Religion
(Protestant Revolution)
|
Renaissance
|
2nd Industrial
|
1700 to 1900
|
Capital
|
Bank
|
Politics (Democratic
Revolution)
|
Enlightenment
|
3rd Information
|
1900 to 2000
|
Knowledge
Workers
|
Modern
Corporation
|
Finance
|
Pragmatism
|
4th Entrepreneurial
|
2000 ~
|
Entrepreneurship
|
Self
|
Business
|
Systems Thinking
|
The West is struggling to create jobs. Continuing to assume
that what limits job creation and economic progress is a lack of capital when
trillions sit idle in banks and corporate accounts, or even knowledge workers
when the most educated generation in history struggles to find work suggests
that we’re clinging to old models of the world in the face of new realities.
Assuming instead that what limits us is entrepreneurship – and beginning to
make the changes that focus on overcoming that limit – could be the key not
just to getting back to the healthy job growth of past decades but to the most
healthy and innovative economy the West has yet created.
No comments:
Post a Comment